People's Democracy(Weekly Organ of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) |
Vol.
XXVIII
No. 38 September 19, 2004 |
Why
Review Of Electricity Act, 2003 Is A Must
Employees
& Engineers Moot Alternative Proposals
Following
are excerpts from the memorandum submitted to the prime minister, Dr Manmohan
Singh, on September 7 by six major unions and federations in the power sector
regarding the Electricity Act, 2003. The six are: Akhil Bharatiya Vidyut Mazdoor
Sangh, All India Federation of Electricity Employees, All India Federation of
Power Diploma Engineers, All India Power Engineers Federation, National
Working Group on Power Sector, and Electricity Employees Federation of India.
THE
UPA government has announced a National Common Minimum Programme for
implementation in which they have stated “Electricity Act, 2003 will be
reviewed” and the prime minister in his address to the nation has stated
“Higher rates of economic growth, modernisation of agriculture and
urbanisation will continue to increase the demand for energy. This demand can
only be met with new investment, increased efficiency and rational pricing. Even
as we plan to make more efficient use of conventional sources of energy, we must
invest in the development of non-conventional sources.
We will evolve an energy policy package that will cover all sources of
energy and will address all aspects like energy security, access and
availability, affordability and pricing, efficiently and environment.”
The
last 15 years experiences of the power sector reforms, driven by the policy of
liberalisation and privatisation, in a nutshell are:
The
new Electricity Act proposed separation of rural India from the urban. The
power supply for the peasantry and rural area is left out to local self
-governments, NGOs etc.
In
the name of resource crunch, private monopolies, both foreign and Indian,
were invited for power generation as Independent Power Producers (IPPs) and
offered major incentives. Among the incentives were a guaranteed return on
equity at 16 per cent, higher rate of depreciation to an average of 8.04 per
cent, higher operation and maintenance cost related to the project cost,
full reimbursement of income tax treating it as a pass through item to
tariff, treating the exchange rate variation as a pass through item to
tariff, etc.
This
resulted in an increase in cost of power. Central Public Sector
Organisations also exploited the situation and increased power cost like
other IPPs, hastening the process of SEBs becoming sick and resulting in a
more than three-fold increase in the cost of power supply.
The
high price of electricity in the country led to closure of industries in
many areas and was making Indian industry non-competitive. India’s power
tariff for industry is currently one of the highest in the world. The story
of agriculture sector needs no narration.
The
power requirement of the country has been inflated purposely, creating a
panic situation and allowing for more and more concessions to private and
foreign capital.
The
fuel policy has been changed for using hydrocarbons for power generation.
The use of naphtha as fuel has led to huge increases in the costs of such
power.
The
power losses and theft under the SEBs has been exaggerated up to and above
50 per cent and in the name of improving efficiencies, the SEBs are being
dismantled.
The
cross subsidy system in vogue has been changed and tariff rates for the
peasants and poor sections have been increased – in almost all cases
faster than for other sections.
The
private operators who entered the field failed to fulfill their contract and
hence power shortages have become a continuing process.
We need not detail here the experience of Orissa, Andhra Pradesh, and
the latest in Delhi or the notorious experience of Enron in Maharashtra.
ALTERNATIVE
FRAMEWORK
This
is, in short, our experience of the reform period. In this context we are
offering an alternative framework to that contained in the Electricity Act, 2003
based on our experience.
The
engineers and employees in the power sector are of the firm view that the
Electricity (Supply) Act 1948 was the appropriate instrument for the development
of the electricity supply industry in the country. We have strong reservations
on the need for enacting the Electricity Act, 2003 as it fails to address the
core concerns of the power sector, such as the need to reduce the cost of
electricity, customer satisfaction, rural electrification and the necessity for
electricity service to have a universal service obligation.
The Act has not led to the reduction of the subsidy burden on the
government; it merely shifts the nature and content of the subsidy.
The Electricity Supply Act 1948 was a time-tested legislation that has
enabled the growth and development of the electrical power supply industry in
the country. It enabled private
sector participation, open access and trading consistent with public interest.
What it does not allow is unbridled profits to investors and speculation
in power. Major improvements in the
functioning of the electricity industry can be brought about within the
framework of the Electricity Supply Act 1948.
The problem was not with the legislation but with the implementation of
the legislation. We, the engineers
and the employees of the electricity power supply industry therefore demand that
the Electricity (Supply) Act 1948 be restored.
AMENDMENTS
PROPOSED
Without
prejudice to the above demand in view of the intention expressed in the Common
Minimum Programme (CMP) of the United Progressive Alliance to review the
Electricity Act, 2003 we are proposing a set of amendments that need to be made
in the present legislation.
In
the Statement of Objectives
Service
to the customer and extension of supply to rural areas should be the
principal objective of the Act. Privatisation
and development of private market for power cannot and should not be the
objective of the Act.
Delivering
power at affordable prices by optimising generation at the least cost.
Ensuring
continued supply at affordable rates to the agricultural sector in order to
sustain food production and food security; to government aided educational
institutions, hospitals, small scale industries including cottage industries
etc.
Ensuring
that this essential public service has an obligation for universal service
provision and is accessible to all citizens and that electricity enables the
balanced and coordinated development of the all regions of the country.
Ensure
that the balance between the centre and the states in the federal structure
of India as envisaged in the Constitution of India and Electricity (Supply)
Act 1948 is not diluted.
Ensure
that the wealth and assets created by the Indian people is not taken over by
Indian and foreign monopolies.
Rights
and privileges of the employees should be safeguarded.
Enable
the conservation of energy through suitable instruments in demand side
management and proper choice and use of fuels.
The
profits of a regulated sector like power should be capped based on the prime
RBI lending rate and not an arbitrary figure such as 16 per cent. This
should be part of the Act as it was in the 1948 Act. The depreciation rate
should also be realistic in line with the anticipated life of the plant.
Cross-subsidies
should continue in the tariff formulation subject to an upper limit beyond
which it will have to be direct subsidy from the government.
Power
should be made available at affordable rates to all sections of the people
with special provision for agriculture.
Electricity
development has to correct the very large regional imbalances that exist in
the country.
Tariff
is to be fixed by the concerned governments. The regulatory authorities
should only be responsible for an equitable implementation of such policies.
In
State Electricity Boards
Fundamental
Issues: Generation,
transmission and distribution are closely interconnected activities that need to
be coordinated in a holistic manner. Considering
the importance of electricity as an essential intermediate input for economic
development, there is a distinct advantage in integrating the activities within
a single organisational structure. Public
ownership and control is desirable as electricity supply is a utility service
and its control cannot be left to be dictated by the market forces, which would
be detrimental to the interests of a developing country like ours. Experience in
various states has shown that unbundling of the State Electricity Boards (SEBs
with or without privatisation) has not resolved the fundamental problems –
burden of losses to the SEBs; subsidy from the government; T&D and other
commercial losses etc. On the other
hand the other overheads on account of multiple organisations has increased and
so also the coordinated working. Experience
of privatisation in Orissa and Delhi is equally dismal.
The following are the principles for detailing the amendments to the Electricity Act, 2003 regarding SEBs:
The
State Electricity Boards should be retained as they are and restore where
they have been split.
Budgetary
assistance should be made to reimburse the SEBs for sale of electricity
below the cost of production.
Concessions
made to any section of consumers should be made transparent and quantified.
SEBs
should be allowed to be financially viable as envisaged in Section 59 of the
Electricity Supply Act 1948 and the Regulatory Commissions should ensure
their financial viability.
SEBs
must provide supply at defined standards and ensure customer satisfaction
even under conditions of shortages
In
Central Electricity Authority (CEA)
Fundamental
Issues: Electrical Power is
an extremely capital and skill intensive industry. Since its inception sections of the industry have exhibited
cartel and monopoly characteristics. Regulation
of this industry is only possible with technical knowledge. Planning is an
integral part of regulation of the industry.
The
following are the principles for detailing the amendments to the Electricity
Act, 2003 regarding CEA:
CEA
should be the repository of technical excellence in India so as to enable it
to a) prepare a National Power Plan b) provide technical support to the
Regulatory Commissions and governments c) apprise the techno-economic
viability of generation and transmission projects and d) evaluate the
technical and commercial claims of manufacturers and service providers.
CEA
should maintain and regularly publish for public consumption cost and
performance data regarding the power industry. The data should include all
captive generation and all investments made in transmission and distribution
by private and public companies/boards.
CEA
should periodically review and publish the performance of all private or
public distribution companies/boards.
Adherence
to the National Electricity Plan and technical advice of CEA should be made
mandatory.
Techno-economic
clearance of all power projects above 100 MW should be made mandatory.
REBs,
the main instrument of grid control, should be made more effective and
strengthened by restoring RLDCs
with them.
CEA
should be responsible for managing the NLDCs and RLDCs so as to ensure that
they function in a non-commercial and impartial manner.
In
order to ensure high standards, the provision that the chairman of the
authority must be selected from amongst the members should be restored.
In
Regulatory Commissions (RCs)
RCs
should be professional bodies. No
person should be made chairman or member of the RC unless he/she has been
associated with the electrical power industry for a minimum period of 15
years. (Civil servants must only be permitted only if their experience in
industry related postings is more than 10 years)
Appointments
to RCs should be transparent and notified in public in order to invite
objections to the appointment of a person. The selection committee report
should be tabled in the legislature.
The
expenditure of the RCs should be charged on the budget.
The
term “public interest” should be clearly and specifically defined in its
application with regard to the jurisdiction and decisions of the RCs and the
state governments. In case of a
dispute between the RC and the state governments, opinion should be sought
from CEA/appellant tribunal/CERC.
RCs
should have the obligation to review all PPAs entered into before their
coming into force and regulate them in order to enable least cost supply to
the consumer.
Responsibilities,
obligations and powers of the RCs should be clearly defined.
National
Guidelines should be issued by the CERC so that there is some form of
uniformity in the decisions of the SERCs.
In
Generation
“Captive
Generation” must be defined more precisely so as to preclude large
industrial units from making a back door entry into generation and trading
without assuming responsibility for rural electrification that shall remain
in the domain of the SEBs. The captive generators should be regulated and
should pay surcharge to compensate the SEBs for their obligation for
universal service provision.
Hydro
power should not be privatised (A hydro power site is a gift of nature and
is finite, privatising should not be allowed of this finite resource)
There
has to be social control on the techno-economics of power plants.
Choice of fuel and cost of the power plant and consequent cost of
generation must be regulated.
In
Open Access and Trading
“open
access” is meaningless in a situation of supply shortages and shortfall in
transmission capacity. Therefore,
it is neither desirable nor feasible to have unfettered open access.
Provisions
for 2nd licencee for distribution should be removed.
Universal
service obligation is directly hindered by unfettered open access since it
tends to segregate the profitable and the loss making segments of the supply
industry and privatise only the former.
Trading
should be restricted only to the public owned agencies since there is a
grave danger of large speculative profits if there is inadequate regulation.
Under the present conditions of shortages it is not possible to have
on line market regulation, consequently there will be cherry picking and
domestic and agricultural consumers will be the causality.